Revealing Environmental Inequality Hidden in ... - ACS Publications

7 School of Government, Central University of Finance and Economics, ... The unequal exchange of goods and services and associated value added and ...
6 downloads 0 Views 2MB Size
Subscriber access provided by UNIV OF NEW ENGLAND ARMIDALE

Policy Analysis

Revealing Environmental Inequality Hidden in China’s Inter-Regional Trade Wei Zhang, Yu Liu, Kuishuang Feng, Klaus Hubacek, Jinnan Wang, Miao-Miao Liu, Ling Jiang, Hongqiang Jiang, Nianlei Liu, Pengyan Zhang, Ying Zhou, and Jun Bi Environ. Sci. Technol., Just Accepted Manuscript • DOI: 10.1021/acs.est.8b00009 • Publication Date (Web): 25 May 2018 Downloaded from http://pubs.acs.org on May 25, 2018

Just Accepted “Just Accepted” manuscripts have been peer-reviewed and accepted for publication. They are posted online prior to technical editing, formatting for publication and author proofing. The American Chemical Society provides “Just Accepted” as a service to the research community to expedite the dissemination of scientific material as soon as possible after acceptance. “Just Accepted” manuscripts appear in full in PDF format accompanied by an HTML abstract. “Just Accepted” manuscripts have been fully peer reviewed, but should not be considered the official version of record. They are citable by the Digital Object Identifier (DOI®). “Just Accepted” is an optional service offered to authors. Therefore, the “Just Accepted” Web site may not include all articles that will be published in the journal. After a manuscript is technically edited and formatted, it will be removed from the “Just Accepted” Web site and published as an ASAP article. Note that technical editing may introduce minor changes to the manuscript text and/or graphics which could affect content, and all legal disclaimers and ethical guidelines that apply to the journal pertain. ACS cannot be held responsible for errors or consequences arising from the use of information contained in these “Just Accepted” manuscripts.

is published by the American Chemical Society. 1155 Sixteenth Street N.W., Washington, DC 20036 Published by American Chemical Society. Copyright © American Chemical Society. However, no copyright claim is made to original U.S. Government works, or works produced by employees of any Commonwealth realm Crown government in the course of their duties.

Page 1 of 20

Environmental Science & Technology

1

Revealing Environmental Inequality Hidden in China’s Inter-Regional Trade

2 3

Wei Zhang1,2,‡, Yu Liu3,4,‡, Kuishuang Feng5, Klaus Hubacek5,6, Jinnan Wang1,2*, Miaomiao Liu1, Ling Jiang7, Hongqiang Jiang2, Nianlei Liu2, Pengyan Zhang8, Ying Zhou2 and Jun Bi1*

4

1 State Key Laboratory of Pollution Control and Resource Reuse, School of the Environment, Nanjing University, Nanjing 210023,

5

China

6

2 State Environmental Protection Key Laboratory of Environmental Planning and Policy Simulation, Chinese Academy for

7

Environmental Planning, Beijing 100012, China

8

3 Institutes of Science and Development, Chinese Academy of Sciences, Beijing 100190, China

9

4 School of Public Policy and Management, University of Chinese Academy of Sciences, Beijing 100049, China

10

5 Department of Geographical Sciences, University of Maryland, College Park, Maryland 20742, United States

11

6 Department of Environmental Studies, Masaryk University, Brno 60200, Czech Republic

12

7 School of Government, Central University of Finance and Economics, Beijing 100081, China

13

8 College of Environment and Planning, Henan University, Kaifeng 475004, China

14

Abstract: Trade among regions or countries allows not only the exchange of goods and services but also leads to the

15

transfer of pollution. The unequal exchange of goods and services and associated value added and pollution may be

16

subject to environmental inequality in China given that Chinese provinces are in different development stages. By using

17

the latest multiregional input-output tables and the sectoral air pollutant emission inventory in 2012, we traced

18

emissions and value added along China’s domestic supply chains. Here we show that approximately 62%~76% of the

19

consumption-based air pollution emissions of richer regions (Beijing-Tianjin, East Coast and South Coast) were

20

outsourced to other regions; however, approximately 70% of value added triggered by these region’s final consumption

21

was retained within the region. Some provinces in western China, such as Guizhou, Ningxia and Yunnan, not only

22

incurred net pollution inflows but also suffered negative balance of value added when trading with rich provinces.

23

Addressing such inequalities could not only provide a basis for determining each province’s responsibility for pollution

24

control but also a model for other emerging economies.

25

Table of Contents (TOC)

26 1

ACS Paragon Plus Environment

Environmental Science & Technology

27

1. Introduction

28

China is suffering from serious regional air pollution, caused by rapid urbanization, heavy industrialization and a

29

coal-based energy structure1. Over the 2010~2015 period, China accounted for approximately 50% of global coal

30

consumption2, produced 48% of global steel products3, and thus contributed approximately 30% of global emissions of

31

sulphur dioxide (SO2) and 20% of nitrogen oxides (NOx)4, 5 each year. In 2016, 75.1% of 338 monitored cities failed to

32

reach China’s Grade II standard for air quality (≤35 µg/m3) and the annual average PM2.5 concentration in monitored

33

cities was 4.7 times World Health Organization guidelines (≤10 µg/m3)6. Monitoring data and remote sensing

34

observations indicate that frequent wide-range haze plagues populous economic regions, such as the

35

Beijing-Tianjin-Hebei region, the Yangtze River Delta, the Pearl River Delta7-10, which has become one of the most

36

pressing environmental problems and significantly impacts public health11, 12. Moreover, extensive cross-border physical

37

transport of airborne pollutants amplifies regional problems13. For example, approximately 30% of PM2.5 in Beijing is

38

from surrounding areas14. Thus, the State Council – China’s highest policymaking body – released a national action plan

39

for air pollution control in 2013, which emphasized cross-provincial collaboration on air pollution control and set

40

provinces’ targets for reducing air pollutant emissions mostly based on their territorial emissions15.

41

However, this policy ignores the transfer of responsibility hidden in products exchanged among provinces. The

42

Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) hypothesis states that per capita emissions may decline in relative or absolute

43

terms with increasing per capita income growth after per capita wealth in the country/region reached to a turning point 16,

44

17

45

pollution to low income regions with less strict environmental regulation according to the pollution haven

46

hypothesis18-21. Generally speaking, the provinces with more pollution-intensive industries (thermal power, steel,

47

cement, etc.) and a carbon-intensive energy mix bear the cost of the incurring air pollution22-24. From another

48

perspective, exporting pollution-intensive products also stimulates economic growth in less developed provinces. For

49

example, as the largest producer of iron, steel and cement in China, the relatively low-income province Hebei, gained

50

46% of its GDP via exports of industrial products to other provinces. Hence, both transferred economic benefits and air

51

pollutant emissions embodied in inter-regional trade should be considered when designing policies for cross-regional

52

collaboration.

. However, other evidence shows that the reduction in pollution emissions is to some extent due to the outsourcing

53

Ecologically Unequal Exchange (EUE) is generally understood as the unequal material exchange relations among

54

countries holding different positions in the world-system25-27, and were mostly found between “core” countries (e.g. the

55

United States) and “peripheral” countries28, 29. Recent research operationalized EUE by tracing and comparing flows of

56

trade-embodied wealth and pollution along global supply chains30-32. China, as the world’s factory, plays the role of a

57

“semi-core” country in the global trade network but also suffers from environmental inequality from developed

58

countries33, 34. Therefore, establishing shared responsibility for pollution between rich consumers and poor producers

59

can mitigate some of the problems caused by EUE globally, and also within countries such as China with serious wealth

60

and pollution inequalities35-37. At present, most previous studies have focused on trade-embodied emissions22, 38, their

2

ACS Paragon Plus Environment

Page 2 of 20

Page 3 of 20

Environmental Science & Technology

61

related contributions to air quality39, 40 or public health41-43 and, to some extent, the unequal relationships between

62

developed and less developed regions within China. However, the economic-environmental inequality hidden of China’s

63

inter-regional trade has seldom been quantified. The quantification of unequal exchange of environmental pollution and

64

value added may provide not only the basis for determining each province’s responsibility for pollution control but also

65

a model for other emerging economies.

66

Using the latest multiregional input-output (MRIO) model and air pollutant emission inventories, this paper built

67

consumption-based inventories of air pollution emissions and value added by tracking air pollution and contribution to

68

value added along the entire intra- and inter-regional supply chain in China. Moreover, a regional environmental

69

inequality (REI) index was developed to represent the relative degree of inequality between a pair of provinces by

70

employing net transfers of emissions and value added associated with inter-provincial trade, which is different from

71

other inequality indices such as the pollution-wealth or emissions-wealth ratio29, 32. These indices merely displayed the

72

mismatch of some country’s economic gains and emissions when trading with other countries. Additionally, a measure

73

called atmospheric pollutant equivalents (APE) was introduced to comprehensively represent the severity of air

74

pollution. The details of the MRIO model, emission inventories, REI index and APE are presented in the Materials and

75

Methods section and Supporting Information (SI). It is important to note that the focus of this study is the transfer of air

76

pollutant emissions and economic gain associated with inter-regional exchange of goods and services within China.

77

Emissions and value added embodied in international exports are excluded in our analysis. Additionally,

78

production-based accounting in this study refers to all emissions and value added associated with the production of

79

goods and services within a region, whereas consumption-based accounting refers to all emissions and value added

80

(also referred as embodied or virtual emissions or value added) associated with the production along the entire supply

81

chain across regions to meet final consumption in a region.

82

2. Materials and Methods

83

2.1 MRIO Analysis

84

An input-output model is a quantitative economic approach for analysing flows of goods and services between

85

economic sectors of a region or country based on input-output tables. The advantage of using an input-output model is

86

its ability to capture the direct and indirect (supply chain) effects of final consumption of goods and service in a country

87

or region captured through the Leontief inverse matrix44, 45, which captures the infinite round by round production

88

effects triggered by final demand. MRIO to further track economic flows between sectors and consumers of different

89

regions and thus is able to characterize the supply chain relationships between regions and between economic sectors46.

90

The environmentally extended MRIO approach can reveal resource consumption and emissions in other regions caused

91

by the consumption of a focal region47. MRIO analysis has been widely applied to international and inter-regional

92

transfers of carbon dioxide48, 49, water50, 51, atmosphere pollution22, 23, 52 and public health impacts41-43.

93

Here, there are n sectors and m regions. r and s represent exporting and importing regions, i and j represent exporting

94

and importing sectors. In this paper, matrices are indicated by italicized capital letters; vectors are denoted by bold, 3

ACS Paragon Plus Environment

Environmental Science & Technology

Page 4 of 20

95

italicized lower case letters. In addition, scalars are presented by italicized lower case letters. Here, x is a mn×1 vector

96

r with its element xi , representing the output of sector i in region r due to domestic consumption; y is a mn×1 vector

97

rs with its element yi representing the products of sector i from region r consumed finally in region s. A is a mn×mn

98

matrix with its element aijrs , the direct consumption coefficient, representing the requirement from sector i in region r to

99

produce per unit output for sector j in region s. Note that we focus only on the transfer of air pollution and economic

100

benefits within China and international export is not considered in this paper. The horizontal accounting balance of the

101

monetary MRIO table (SI Table S1) can be written as following,

102

x = ( I − A)−1 × y

103 104 105

(1)

−1 Here, (I − A) is the Leontief inverse matrix, the element of which represents the direct and indirect consumption

of products of sector i in region r needed by sector j in region s to make a unit of final product. Let mn×1 vectors f = ( fi r ) and d = (dir ) refer to sectoral air pollution emissions intensity (SO2, NOx and PM)

106

r r r r r r and value added coefficient for each region, respectively. The respective elements f i = ki xi and d i = vi xi

107

r r represent the air pollutant emissions and value added per unit of total output, where ki and vi represent air pollutant

108

emissions and value added of sector i in region r. Here, the notation ^ indicates the diagonalization of corresponding

109

column vectors.

110

s r Let yˆ and yˆ refer to the diagonal matrixes with the corresponding sectoral products consumption for region s

111

and r (r≠s), but zeroes for all other regions, respectively; let fˆ r and fˆ s represent the diagonal matrixes with

112

corresponding sectoral air pollution emissions intensity of region s and r (r≠s), but zeroes for all other regions. Then

113

we have following equations,

114

E sr = fˆ r ( I − A) −1 yˆ s

(2)

115

E rs = fˆ s ( I − A) −1 yˆ r

(3)

116

EN = E rs − E sr

(4)

117

Here, the matrix E sr refers to the emissions of region r induced by the consumption of region s, that is,

118

trade-embodied emissions flow/transfer from region s to r; and the matrix E rs refers to the emissions in region s

119

induced by the consumption of region r, that is, trade-embodied emissions flow/transfer from region r to s. The matrix

120

EN refers to the net flows of emissions between region r and s. Note that there are both positive and negative value in

121

EN. The positive value means outflows from region r to s, and negative value exactly means inflows from r to s, that is,

122

outflows from s to r. Here, EN is defined as the matrix with all positive value of emissions flows among regions for

123

following calculation of REI index.

4

ACS Paragon Plus Environment

Page 5 of 20

124 125

Environmental Science & Technology

Similarly, let dˆ r and dˆ s represent the diagonal matrixes with corresponding value added coefficients of region s and r (r≠s), but zeroes for all other regions. Then we have following equations,

126

V sr = dˆ r ( I − A) −1 yˆ s

127

V rs = dˆ s ( I − A) −1 yˆ r

128

VN = V rs − V sr

(5)

(6)

(7)

129

Here, matrix V sr refers to the value added of region r induced by the consumption of region s, that is,

130

trade-embodied value added flow/transfer from region s to r; and matrix V rs refers to the value added in region s

131

induced by the consumption of region r. that is, trade-embodied value added flow/transfer from region r to s; matrix VN

132

refers to the net flows of value added between region r and s. Note that there are both positive and negative value in VN.

133

2.2 Regional Environmental Inequality Index

134

We employ the REI index to evaluate unequal transfers between Atmospheric Pollutant Equivalents (APE) emissions

135

and value added associated with inter-provincial trade. Here, e rs and v rs are the corresponding elements in matrices

136

EN and VN, respectively; v rs

137 138

Assuming there is ∀Bm×m with its element b, then we normalize all elements of B to range between 0 and 1 using following general equation:

f (b ) =

139

140 141

142

is the absolute value of v rs .

Here,

b − bmin bmax − bmin

(8)

bmax and bmin represent the maximum and minimum values of b, respectively. Therefore, we can obtain the

matrix of REI index,

Q = (q rs )m×m , whose element q rs can be calculated as follows:  e rs f ( rs ) , if e rs > 0 and v rs > 0  q rs =  v  f (e rs ) + f ( v rs ) + 1 , if e rs > 0 and v rs < 0 

(9)

143

Because e rs >0, which is stated in the definition of EN , there are two types of relationship between region r and

144

region s. When e rs >0 and v rs >0, both APE and value added outsourcing occur from region r to region s, and the

145

elements in matrix e rs v rs are normalized to range between 0 and 1. When region r outsources more APE and less

146

value added to region s, the value of q will be greater (close to 1). When e rs >0 and v rs